January 21, 2025

Why Your Netflix Traffic is Slow, and Why the Open Internet Order Won't (Necessarily) Make It Faster

The FCC recently released the Open Internet Order, which has much to say about “net neutrality” whether (and in what circumstances) an Internet service provider is permitted to prioritize traffic. I’ll leave more detailed thoughts on the order itself to future posts; in this post, I would like to clarify what seems to be a fairly widespread misconception about the sources of Internet congestion, and why “net neutrality” has very little to do with the performance problems between Netflix and consumer ISPs such as Comcast.

Much of the popular media has led consumers to believe that the reason that certain Internet traffic—specifically, Netflix video streams—were experiencing poor performance because Internet service providers are explicitly slowing down Internet traffic. John Oliver accuses Comcast of intentionally slowing down Netflix traffic (an Oatmeal cartoon reiterates this claim). These caricatures are false, and they demonstrate a fundamental misunderstanding of how Internet connectivity works, what led to the congestion in the first place, and the economics of how the problems were ultimately resolved.

In fact, while there are certainly many valid arguments to support an open Internet, “faster Netflix” turns out to be a relatively unrelated concern. Contrary to what many have been led to believe, there is currently no evidence to suggest that Comcast made an explicit decision to slow down streaming traffic; rather, the slowdown resulted from high volumes of streaming video, which congested Internet links between the video content and the users themselves.  Who is “at fault” for creating that congestion, who is responsible for mitigating that congestion, and who should pay to increase capacity are all important (and contentious) questions to which there are no simple answers. To say that “net neutrality” will fix this problem, however, reflects a fundamental misunderstanding.  Below, I explain what actually caused the congestion, how the problem was ultimately resolved, and why the prevailing issue has more to do with Internet economics and market power than it does with policies like network neutrality.

A (simplified) illustration of how Comcast users actually stream Netflix traffic (early 2013).  Internet paths between consumers (“eyeballs”) and content typically traverse multiple Internet service providers.  For example, prior to March 2014, there were several paths between Comcast and Netflix via multiple “transit providers”, including Cogent, Level 3, Tata, and others.  In all of these cases, Netflix paid these transit providers for connectivity to Comcast customers.  Comcast, in contrast, had what is called a “settlement-free peering” (or, “peering” for short) relationship with each of these transit providers, where Comcast and each of these providers deemed it mutually beneficial to interconnect.

So far, all is normal Internet economics: parties who garner benefit from interconnection pay their “providers” for Internet connectivity, as Netflix did with its transit providers; parties who see mutual benefit in interconnecting do not exchange money.

The Internet slows down (mid-2013 through early 2014). Around mid-2013, Comcast users (and other users) began to see congested Internet paths to various Internet destinations, not only to Netflix, but also to other Internet destinations. This phenomenon occurred because the video traffic was congesting paths not only to Netflix, but also paths to other destinations that had some path segments in common with paths to Netflix.  In our ongoing BISmark project, we continually collect measurements from hundreds of home networks around the world.  In mid-2013, we noticed and documented this congestion; our findings showed that this congestion, visible as extremely high latency, appeared on paths to many Internet destinations.  The plot below shows an one consumer Internet connection that we measured in January 2014, which routinely experienced high latency to many Internet destinations every evening during “prime time”—oddly coinciding with peak video streaming hours from home networks. A “normal” latency plot would show flat lines, reflecting latencies that roughly correspond to the speed of light along that end-to-end path (plus small amounts of queueing).  In contrast, the plot below shows striking diurnal latency spikes.

When we noticed this phenomenon, we raised it to Comcast’s attention.  As it turns out, Comcast already knew about it, and it was clear how to solve the problem: Connect directly to Netflix with high-capacity links.  The question was: who should pay for the interconnection? Comcast or Netflix?

The peering dispute: Who should pay? (late 2013 to early 2014) For a period of several months, while Comcast and Netflix were sorting out the answer to this question, Comcast customers experienced routinely high latency during peak hours, undoubtedly caused by congestion induced by video streaming.  At this point (and as documented in opposing FCC filings), each side had a story to tell:

  • Netflix claims that they were paying for transit to Comcast customers through their transit ISPs, and that they should not be responsible for upgrading the (congested) peering links between Comcast and the transit providers.  The FCC declaration went so far as to claim that Comcast was intentionally letting peering links congest (see paragraph 29 of the declaration) to force Netflix to pay for direct connectivity.  (Here is precisely where the confusion with net neutrality and paid prioritization comes into play, but this is not about paid prioritization, but rather about who should pay who for connectivity.  More on that later.)
  • Comcast claims that Netflix was sending traffic at such high volumes as to intentionally congest the links between different transit ISPs and Comcast, essentially taking a page from Norton’s “peering playbook” and forcing Comcast and its peers (i.e., the transit providers, Cogent, Level 3, Tata, and others) to upgrade capacity one-by-one, before sending traffic down a different path, congesting that, and forcing an upgrade. Their position was that Netflix was sending more traffic through these transit providers than the transit providers could handle, and thus that Netflix or their transit providers should pay to connect to Comcast directly. Comcast also implies that certain transit providers such as Cogent are likely the source of congested paths, a claim that has been explored but not yet conclusively proved one way or the other, owing to the difficulty of locating these points of congestion (more on that in a future post).

Resolving the dispute: Paid peering (March 2014). Both sides of this argument are reasonable and plausible—this is a classic “peering dispute”, which is nothing new on the Internet; in the past, these disputes have even partitioned the Internet, keeping some users on the Internet from communicating with others.  The main difference in the recent peering dispute is that the stakes are higher. The loser of this argument is essentially who blinks first. The best technical solution (and what ultimately happened) is that Netflix and Comcast should interconnect directly.  But, who should pay for that interconnection? Should Netflix pay Comcast, since Netflix depends on reaching its subscribers, many of whom are Comcast customers?  Or, should Comcast pay Netflix, since Comcast subscribers would be unhappy with poor Netflix performance? This is where market leverage comes into play: Because most consumers do not have choice in broadband Internet providers, Comcast arguably (and, empirically speaking, as well) has more market leverage: They can afford to ask Netflix to pay for that direct link—a common Internet business relationship called paid peering—because they have more market power. This is exactly what happened, and once Netflix paid Comcast for the direct peering link, congestion was relieved and performance returned to normal.  Note: Despite how popular media might present matters, this is not paid prioritization (which would amount to Comcast asking Netflix to pay for higher priority), but rather Internet economics that has borne itself out in peculiar ways because of the market structures.

Whether or not it is “right” that Comcast has such leverage is perhaps a philosophical debate, but it is also worth remembering that the classification of the Internet as an information service (regulation that the government is now backtracking on) is part of what got us into this situation in the first place. And, while it is also worth considering whether the impending merger between Comcast and Time Warner Cable might exacerbate the current situation, I predict that this is unlikely.  In general, as one access ISP gains more market share, a content provider such as Netflix depends on connectivity to that ISP even more, potentially extracting increasingly higher prices for interconnection.  In the specific case of Comcast and Time Warner, it is difficult to predict exactly how much additional leverage this will create, but as it turns out, these two ISPs are already in markets where they are not competing with one another, so this specific merger is unlikely to dramatically change the current situation.

Various technical and policy solutions could change the landscape, or at least mitigate these problems.  Among them, fair queueing at interconnection points to ensure that one type of traffic does not clobber the performance of other traffic flows, might help mitigate some of these problems in the short term. The types of prioritization that the Open Internet Order deals with are, interestingly, one way of coping with congested links. Note that the Open Internet Order does not prohibit all prioritization, only paid prioritization.  Thus, we will certainly see ISPs continue to use prioritization to manage congestion—prioritization is, in fact, a necessary tool for managing limited resources such as bandwidth. The real solution, however, likely has little to do with prioritization at all and more likely hinges on increased competition among access ISPs.

Comments

  1. Lawrence D’Oliveiro says

    “Because most consumers do not have choice in broadband Internet providers, Comcast arguably (and, empirically speaking, as well) has more market leverage”

    In other words, if there were more market competition, Comcast would not be in a position to demand payment from Netflix. Comcast is abusing its market dominance to obtain such a payment. In a competitive market, it would be the ISPs paying Netflix for supplying a service that attracts their customers. The bits flow from Netflix to the ISP; because those bits have value, the money should be flowing the other way.

  2. I know for certain somethings wrong with the routing. Ive spoken to a few people about this issue and they say the isps blame the peering point and the peering point blames the isp… Sorry im not too technically inclined but i have an inkling that whats being discussed here is directly connected to the latency issues ive experienced the past few months using different isps

  3. I’m do not know too much about whats been said but i think my issue currently has to do with whats being discussed.

    I play a certain video game and ive noticed that my latency has increased for almoat every single server destination in America to the point where the game is simply not playable.

    I had time warner and had this issue. Ok so i switched to att… Still have the same issue. I just switched to charter and it has the same latency issue as well. These last 6 months have been really bad. So i thought ok the servers the issue but ive tried various servers throughout the US and they all have the same latency issue. It doesnt matter which ISP i use it seems like all the west coast isps produce the same lag. Ive tried two different pcs and i know its not the game itself because ive played the game on lan and everythings normal.

    What I’m experiencing has to do with whats being discussed here… The only question i have is… When will it be fixed?

  4. Anonymous says

    “In the specific case of Comcast and Time Warner, it is difficult to predict exactly how much additional leverage this will create, but as it turns out, these two ISPs are already in markets where they are not competing with one another, so this specific merger is unlikely to dramatically change the current situation.”

    It is hard to know if that statement was intentionally obtuse or simply disingenuous.

    Market leverage derives from the total number customers controlled in the form of residential endpoints. The whole art of the exercise is to exploit that grip which defeats any hope for open market dynamic, which “free market” religion obscures but cannot hide.

    If this were not a duopoly becoming a monopoly one might say the customers served, but these customers are captive. Geography is an irrelevant dimension of the economic power relationship. They literally have nowhere else to go in cyber or geo space. The deregulation of the 1990s was complete political economic fraud now bearing its inevitable poisonous fruit to the public interest with lousy expensive service from the most customer hated companies in the country (take that Delta Airlines, amazing someone beat you, but you were part of that same era of economic de-regulation weren’t you) and grossly huge gains solely benefiting a tiny economic elite. Thirty years of Reaganomics will do that to a nation.

    The obvious solutions are a) real competition, something that financial Capitalism and the political tools it controls (called Congressmen) will never permit, aided of course by “technical expertise” in pay of advancing the status quo as inviolate, and b) at least an even split of costs.

  5. Philip Levis says

    I thought this issue would go away if Comcast would deploy OCAs? It’s my understanding that ISPs in competitive markets are delighted to deploy them.

    Is the basic economic question whether Comcast can pursue rent-seeking behavior? If the argument is that Comcast needs payment from Netflix in order to finance the upgrade of its network, I don’t think that holds up given where OCAs could be placed. There are open ports, Netflix’s colo is next to Comcast’s, and the cost is a cable. Or is there any demonstration that Netflix traffic is causing internal congestion in Comcast’s network? The analogy there is that you want payment to connect someone’s road to yours because the resulting traffic is more than your road could support. I’d note that the issue is not Comcast or Verizon generally, but only locations/situations where they have a monopoly.

    That being said John Oliver’s presentation, while hilarious, definitely has some holes in it. 🙂

  6. Is the debate over the Netflix event sort of tangential to the core question of whether or not the goal of Net Neutrality remains valid?
    It was my impression that what NetNeutrality was about *preventing* carriers from arbitrarily discriminating [in the future]. Will it?
    I favored NN because (if I understood it correctly) it meant that Comcast couldn’t decide to throttle its competitors’ traffic; it would be required to treat competitors’ as it would treat its own content, thus removing the temptation to throttle them in order to drive customers to its own services.
    But perhaps I misunderstood.

  7. Another reader writes me privately: “Nice thoughtful article about net neutrality. My only quibble is that I do think that Comcast forcing Netflix to pay for upgrades could be subjectively considered paid prioritization.”

    This is a great point, and this semantic blurriness is at the root of the confusion reflected in the above comments. Who pays whom is an old topic in the economics of Internet connectivity—typically, the side that “benefits more” pays for the interconnect, or sometimes the cost is shared. In fact, in the 2000s, the “tier-1 ISPs” (Level 3, Cogent, AT&T, etc.) were in the rosy position where everyone paid them to connect, regardless of the direction of traffic. It’s interesting and poetic that the tables of the early 2000s are now turned.

    One could reasonably be concerned about Comcast’s ability to extract high prices or force other networks to pay when connecting to it. One could also be concerned about whether Comcast’s market power allows it to extract these high rents to instead encourage people to use Comcast services or consume Comcast/NBC content. But, that relates to competition and market dynamics and is a very different thing than “paid prioritization”, where an ISP would explicitly throttle (or prioritize) traffic and accepting payment for differential treatment.

  8. You sir, have missed the whole reason why Netflix was slow. That “congestion” that was caused happened because some $10 connector cables weren’t where they should be. Even though Netflix agreed to pay for those cables, Comcast was unwilling to hook them up. That **is** slowing things down.

  9. It’s worth noting that the actual peering companies pointed out that this narrative is pretty much false. Verizon in particular chose not to pay a trivially small fee to fix the problem, instead trying to extract much more money from Netflix in the process and to push customers towards it’s own services. http://blog.level3.com/open-internet/verizons-accidental-mea-culpa/

  10. http://media2.policymic.com/9dc9accb3fbb1b53b283f5be708b576f.png

    Really? Comcast didn’t intentionally slow Netflix down?